How many children from each social class
will enter university?
In
Britain today, social class no longer determines our chances in life. A parent’s social class accounts for only 3% of the social class
mobility of their children. The ability
of the individual child accounts for 13%. For all we know, the rest of the
difference may be due to personality or perhaps even physical attractiveness,
but it is not social class. Without
quite realising it, we have achieved considerable social mobility between
generations, with far more of that change being due to ability than to social
class itself.
One
surprising effect of this meritocracy is that social classes still differ in intelligence, simply because the most able have been given a chance to rise into
more demanding jobs, and the less able have been left in less prestigious
occupations. Opportunity has allowed
people to spread out more, and has brought the best brains to bear on the
hardest problems, regardless of their social background. Separately, there has also been “social class
inflation”, with more people doing managerial work, and far fewer in unskilled
manual jobs. These manual classes have been stripped of many of their brighter
people, who have moved upwards as opportunities opened up.
If
entry to university were based solely on intelligence, how many children from each social class would enter university?
Making that calculation depends on some assumptions. First, that people marry
partners of roughly the same intelligence. This seems to be true, in that
married couples are even more concordant for intelligence than they are for
height. Secondly, that some parental
intelligence is passed on to children by genes, and recent heritability
estimates of 66% have been established, on samples of 11,000 children (Haworth
et al. 2009).
Calculating
the estimated intelligence of university applicants
according to the social class of their parents is pretty straightforward. Using
data analysed by Daniel Nettle on the 1958 generation, the average intelligence
score of each social class is multiplied by 66% to get an estimate of the
average intelligence of their children. Since the other 34% of intelligence
differences are not due to parental intelligence, the class averages will all
converge on the population average, a phenomenon known as regression to the
mean. The children of professional parents will fall back somewhat towards the population
average, though they will remain above it. The children of unskilled manual
workers will rise back somewhat towards the average, though they will remain below
it. In this way ability is gradually reshuffled each generation, though not
totally. At the end of this generational process there will be some differences
in the average IQs for each social class. However, these small average
differences translate into substantial differences at the upper reaches of the
intelligence distribution. This is simply because most people’s abilities pile
up in the centre of the intelligence range and there are fewer people at the edges.
A small average group difference leads to into big differences in the numbers
of individuals at rarified levels of IQ.
As
regards university entrance, society can set any cutoff point it likes. The Table shows what could
be expected at various levels of participation. The top 50% was the stated national
aspiration, and incidentally corresponds currently to the percentage of the
school population who get 5 or more A to C grades at GCSE. The top 40% is close
to our current participation level. The top 15% corresponds very roughly to the
old universities, and the top 2% to the most intellectually demanding courses
at the most highly ranked universities. The Table shows that social class differences
are greatest when the cutoff point is set very high, simply as a consequence of
the normal distribution of intelligence.
The point of this exercise is not to say
that entry to university should be based on IQ tests. Universities base entry
on scholastic tests, particularly those that identify the very brightest
candidates. Nor do these calculations lead to setting any particular cutoff
point for university entrance as a whole.
That is a social decision.
The
real point is to explain that different rates of entry to university according
to social class are a direct consequence of a meritocratic society. If people are allowed to rise to the jobs which they merit, (true
of Britain from 1958 to 2000 and most probably beyond), then there will be a slight
but significant difference in the average intelligence of their children. These
differences become quite marked at the outer reaches of the intelligence
distribution, leading to actual university entrance figures being legitimately
different from simple expectations. One
should not expect every social class to have university entrance rates directly
proportional to their numbers in the population, because people are selected
into jobs by ability.
Oddly enough, when we hear that
proportionately more middle class children are going to university we should
reply “So they ought to be, if their parents were correctly selected for their
jobs”.
Percentage of each
social class who will be admitted if the university takes the top 50, 40, 15 or
2 % of the student population
|
Student
IQ
|
Top
50%
|
Top
40%
|
Top
15%
Russell Group
|
Top
2%
Oxbridge
|
Professional
|
104
|
64
|
54
|
26
|
5.0
|
Managerial
|
102
|
56
|
46
|
20
|
3.3
|
Middle
|
98
|
45
|
35
|
13
|
1.7
|
Semi-skilled
|
96
|
39
|
30
|
10
|
1.2
|
Unskilled
|
95
|
34
|
26
|
8
|
0.9
|
References
Nettle, D. (2003) Intelligence and class
mobility in the British population. British Journal of Psychology, 94,
551-561.
CMA Haworth, MJ Wright, M Luciano, NG Martin, EJC de
Geus, CEM van Beijsterveldt,
M Bartels, D Posthuma, DI Boomsma, OSP Davis, Y Kovas,
RP Corley, JC DeFries, JK Hewitt, RK Olson, S-A Rhea, SJ Wadsworth, WG Iacono,
M McGue, LA Thompson, SA Hart, SA Petrill, D Lubinski and R Plomin (2009) The heritability of general cognitive ability
increases linearly from childhood to young adulthood. Molecular Psychiatry 1–9.